1996
Gary Bornstein, D. B., & Zamir, S. . (1996).
Cooperation in Intergroup, N-Person and Two-Person Games of Chicken.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 1, Journal of Conflict Resolution 41 (1997), 384-406. Retrieved from
/files/ 96.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractThis paper introduces a new team game where players are engaged in simultaneous games of Chicken between and within teams. The intergroup Chicken game is proposed as a model of intergroup confrontations (e.g., military Conflicts, industrial disputes) involving bilateral threats where a failure on the part of either side to yield leads to an outcome (e.g., war, strike) that is disastrous to both sides. We report an experiment in which an intergroupChicken game with two players in each team was compared with a two-person Chicken and a (single-group) four-person Chicken. The games were played repeatedly and each round was preceded by a pre-game period in which players could signal their intention to cooperate or not. Our interest was in assessing the ability of the participants in the different games to cooperate, i.e., achieve the coordination necessary for the optimal realization of their mutual interests. We found that subjects were considerably less cooperative in the inter-group Chicken game than in either the two-person or the four-person game. Since the coordination problem in the intergroup game is of the same magnitude as that in the four-person game, we attribute most of the competitiveness observed in the intergroup conflict to the strategic properties of the game rather than the number of players involved.
Peleg, B. . (1996).
Effectivity Functions, Game Forms, Games, and Rights.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 1, Social Choice and Welfare 15 (1998), 67-80. Also In: Freedom in Economics, J-F. Laslier, M. Fleurbaey, N. Gravel & A. Trannoy (eds), Routledge, London (1998), 116-132. Retrieved from
/files/dp140.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractIn this paper we offer an axiomatic approach for the investigation of rights by means of game forms. We give a new definition of constitution which consists of three components: the set of rights, the assignment of rights to groups of members of the society, and the distribution of power in the society (as a function of the distribution of rights). Using the forgoing definition we investigate game forms that faithfully represent the distribution of power in the society, and allow the members of the society to exercise their rights simultaneously. Several well-known examples are analyzed in the light of our framework. Finally, we find a connection between Sen's minimal liberalism and Maskin's result on implementation by Nash equilibria.
Gary Bornstein, E. W., & Goren, H. . (1996).
Experimental Study of Repeated Team-Games.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 1, European Journal of Political Economy 12 (1996), 629-639. Retrieved from
/files/dp95.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractWe report an experiment in which the Intergroup Prisoner's Dilemma (IPD) game was contrasted with a structurally identical (single-group) Prisoner's Dilemma (PD). The games were played repeatedly for 40 rounds. We found that subjects were initially more likely to cooperate in the IPD game than in the PD game. However, cooperation rates decreased as the game progressed and, as a result, the differences between the two games disappeared. This pattern is consistent with the hypothesis that subjects learn the structure of the game and adapt their behavior accordingly. Computer simulations based on a simple learning model by Roth & Erev (1995) support this interpretation.
Tamar Keasar, U. M., & Shmida, A. . (1996).
Exploration Effort in Foraging Bees Is Enhanced by Clustering of Food Resources.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 11. Retrieved from
' Publisher's VersionAbstractForaging can be viewed as a dual activity: a food-collection process, and an exploration process, which enables foragers to collect information on food resources. Exploration of food sources may involve patch sampling, as well as sampling of various food sources within heterogeneous patches. The present study aimed to quantify exploration effort in relation to the spatial distribution of the food sources. Exploration effort was measured in two-stage laboratory experiments on naive bumblebees, Bombus terrestris (L.). In the first stage the bees were allowed to forage on three types of color-distinct artificial flowers. In the second stage a new type of artificial flowers ("exploratory flowers"), which were non-rewarding, was added. The four types of artificial flowers were either arranged in spatially distinct clusters or randomly intermingled. Two reward schedules were used in each spatial arrangement: constant refilling of visited flowers and probabilistic refilling. The bees' visit to the exploratory flowers were recorded as a measure of exploratory activity, and were related to their previous foraging experience. Bees which experienced a probabilistic reward schedule explored more than bees from the constant-reward treatments. Bees which foraged on clustered flowers directed a larger proportion of their flights to exploratory flowers, and made more visits to these flowers, than bees that foraged on intermingled flowers. This tendency was obtained both in the probabilistic and in the constant reward schedules. The results suggest that bees allocate more effort to the exploration of novel feeding patches than to the exploration of new food types within a known patch.
Michael Landsberger, Jacob Rubinstein, E. W., & Zamir, S. . (1996).
First-Price Auctions When the Ranking of Valutions Is Common Knowledge.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 9, Review of Economic Design 6 (2001), 461-480. Retrieved from
/files/dp117.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractWe consider an augmented version of the symmetric private value auction model with independent types. The augmentation, intended to illustrate reality, concerns information bidders have about their opponents. To the standard assumption that every bidder knows his type and the distribution of types is common knowledge we added the assumption that the ranking of bidders' valuations is common knowledge. This set-up induces a particular asymmetric auction model that raises serious technical difficulties. We prove existence and uniqueness of equilibrium in pure strategies in the two bidder case. We also show that the model generally has no analytic solution. If the distribution of valuations is uniform, both bidders bid pointwise more aggressively relative to the standard symmetric case. However, this property does not apply to all distributions of valuations. Finally, we also provide a numerical solution of equilibrium bid functions for the uniform distribution case.
Tamar Keasar, U. M., & Shmida, A. . (1996).
Foraging as an Exploratory Activity in Bees: The Effect of Patch Variability.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 11. Retrieved from
' Publisher's VersionAbstractForaging can be viewed as a dual activity: a food-collection process, and an exploration process, which enables foragers to sample and evaluate food resources. The exploratory role of foraging was studied in a series of two-stage laboratory experiments on naive bumblebees. In the first stage of the experiments the bees were allowed to forage on three types of artificial flowers, which were arranged in spatially distinct patches. The mean reward offered by the flowers, the variability in reward among feeding patches and the variability of rewards within patches were varied between experimental treatments. In the second stage a new feeding patch, containing non-rewarding flowers, was added. The bees' visits to this patch were recorded as a measure of exploratory activity, and were related to their previous foraging experience. Bees which had experienced within-patch reward variability explored the non-rewarding patch more than bees which had not been previously exposed to within-patch variability. On the other hand, variability in rewards between feeding patches led to lower exploration levels than in the control experiments, which had no between-patch variability. Exploration effort was not affected by the mean overall nectar volume offered to the bees. Some visits to the non-rewarding patch were recorded even when the other patches offered high nectar volumes on each foraging visit. Individuals within the same treatment varied considerably in exploration effort. Possible sources of this variation are discussed. We conclude that exploration effort in bees is independent of foraging experience to some extent. On the other hand, it is also affected by the variability of their food sources.
Milchtaich, I. . (1996).
Generic Uniqueness of Equilibria in Nonatomic Congestion Games.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 1. Retrieved from
' Publisher's VersionAbstractGeneric uniqueness of pure-strategy Nash equilibrium, and uniqueness of the equilibrium outcome, are proved for a class of noncooperative nonatomic (large) games where a player's payoff depends on, and strictly decreases with, the measure of the set of players playing the same (pure) strategy he is playing. If the play of mixed strategies is allowed, then similar results still hold when the assumption of nonatomicity of the measure is removed. Generic uniqueness of the Cournot-Nash equilibrium distribution, corresponding to a description of a game in terms of distribution of player types, is also proved.
Carmen Herrero, M. M., & Villar, A. . (1996).
Individual Rights and Collective Responsibility: The Rights-Egalitarian Solution.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 6, Mathematical Social Sciences 37 (1999), 59-77. Retrieved from
/files/dp106.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractThe problem of distributing a given amount of a divisible good among a set of agents which may have individual entitlements is considered here. A solution tothis problem, called the Rights-Egalitarian Solution, is proposed. This allocation rule divides equally among the agents the difference between the aggregate entitlements and the amount of that good available. A relevant feature of the analysis developed is that no sign restriction is established on the parameters of the model (that is, the aggregate entitlements may exceed or fall short of the amount of the good, agents' rights may be positive or negative, the allocation may involve a redistribution of agents' holdings, etc.). Several characterizations are provided, and its game theoretic properties are analyzed.
Tamar Keasar, U. M., & Shmida, A. . (1996).
Innate Movement Rules in Foraging Bees: Flight Distances Are Affected by Recent Rewards and Are Correlated with Choice of Flower Type.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 11, Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology 39 (1996), 381-388. Retrieved from
/files/db120.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractThe non-random movements patterns of foraging bees are believed to increase their search efficiency. These patterns may be innate, or they may be learned through the bees' early foraging experience. To identify the innate components of foraging rules, we characterized the flight of naive bumble bees, foraging on non-patchy "field" of randomly scattered artificial flowers with three color displays. The flowers were randomly mixed and all three flower types offered equal nectar volumes. Visited flowers were refilled with probability 0.5 Flight distances, flight durations and nectar probing durations were determined and related to the bees' recent experiences. The naive bees exhibited area-restricted search behavior, i.e, flew shorter distances following visits to rewarding flowers than after visits to empty flowers. Additionally , flight distances during flower-type transitions were longer than flight distances between flowers of the same type. The two movements rules operated together: flight distances werelongest for flights between flower types following non-rewarding visits, shortest for within-type flights following rewarding visits. An increase in flight displacement during flower-type shifts was also observed in a second experiment, in which all three types were always rewarding. In this experiment, flower-type shifts were also accompanied by an increase in flight duration. Possible relationships between flight distances, flight durations and flower-type choice are discussed.
El-Yaniv, R. . (1996).
Is It Rational to Be Competitive? On the Decision-Theoretic Foundations of the Competitive Ratio.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 8. Retrieved from
' Publisher's VersionAbstractThe competitive ratio, a performance measure for online algorithms, or alternatively, a decision making criterion for strict uncertainty conditions, has become a popular and accepted approach within theoretical computer science. This paper closely examines this criterion, both by characterizing it with respect to a set of axioms and in comparison to other known criteria for strict uncertainty.
Young, D. P. F., & Peyton, H. . (1996).
Learning with Hazy Beliefs.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 9, Published As: "Learning, Hypothesis Testing, and Nash Equilibrium", Games and Economic Behavior 25 (2003), 73-96. Retrieved from
/files/db115.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractPlayers are rational if they always choose best replies given their beliefs. They are good predictors if the difference between their beliefs and the distribution of the other's actual strategies goes to zero over time. Learning is deterministic if beliefs are fully determined by the initial conditions and the observed data. (Bayesian updating is a particular example). If players are rational' good predictors, and learn deterministically, there are many games for which neither beliefs nor actions converge to a Nash equilibrium. We introduce an alternative approach to learning called prospecting in which players are rational and good predictors, but beliefs have a small random component. In any finite game, and from any initial conditions, prospecting players learn to play arbitrarily close to Nash equilibrium with probability one.
Tauman, S. H., & Yair, . (1996).
Market Crashes Without External Shocks [Revised].
Discussion Papers. presented at the 12, Journal of Business 77 (2004), 1-8. Retrieved from
/files/ crash.html Publisher's VersionAbstractIt is shown here that market crashes and bubbles can arise without external shocks. Sudden changes in behavior may be the result of endogenous information processing. Except for the daily observation of the market, there is no new information, no communication and no coordination between the participants.
Karp, R. E. - Y., & M., R. . (1996).
Nearly Optimal Competitive Online Replacement Policies.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 3, Mathematics of Operations Research 22 (1997), 814-839. Retrieved from
' Publisher's VersionAbstractThis Paper studies the following online replacement problem. There is a real function f(t), called the flow rate, defined over a finite time horizon [0,T]. It is known that m% f(t) % M for some reals 0 % m < M. At time 0 an online player starts to pay money at the rate of f(0). At each time 0 < t % T the player may changeover and continue paying money at the rate f(t). The complication is that each such changeover incures some fixed penalty. The player is called online as at each time t the player knows f only over the time interval [0,t]. The goal of the player is to minimize the total cost comprised of cumulative payment flow plus change over costs. This formulation of the replacement problem has various interesting applications among which are: equipment replacement, supplier replacement, the menu cost problem and mortgagere financing. With respect to the competitive ratio performance measure, this paper seeks to determine the best possible competitive ratio achievable by an online replacement policy. Our results include the following: a general lower bound on the performance of any deterministic policy, a policy that is optimal in several special cases and a simple policy that is approximately optimal.
Milchtaich, I. . (1996).
On Backward Induction Paths and Pure Strategy Nash Equilibria of Congestion Games.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 6, Published As: "Crowding Games Are Sequentially Solvable", International Journal of Game Theory 27 (1998), 501-509. Retrieved from
' Publisher's VersionAbstractIn this note, a congestion game is a noncooperative normal-form game in which the players share a common set of strategies. The payoff a player receives for playing a particular strategy depends only on the total number of players playing that strategy and decreases with that number in a manner which is specific to the particular player. The corresponding sequential move game is the perfect-information extensive-form game in which players choose their plays sequentially rather than simultaneously, and each player knows the plays of the previous players. We show that the backward induction path of this game is a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium of the simultaneous move game. We also show that, by changing the order of movers in the sequential move game, every pure-strategy Nash equilibrium of the simultaneous move game that is not Pareto dominated by another equilibrium can be obtained.
Aumann, R. J. . (1996).
On the State of the Art in Game Theory.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 6, Games and Economic Behavior 24 (1998), 181-210. Also in W. Albers, W. Guth, P. Hammerstein, B. Moldovanu & E. van Damme (eds.), Understanding Strategic Interaction, Essays in Honor of R. Selten, (1996) Springer-Verlag 8-34. Retrieved from
/files/dp108.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractAn interview conducted on June 30, 1995, which is to appear in the Selten Festschrift: Understanding strategic Interaction, edited by Wulf Albers, Werner Guth, Peter Hammerstein, Benny Moldovanu, and Eric van Damme, with the help of Martin Strobel, to be published by Springer in 1996. The interview ranges over a wide variety of topics related to Game Theory, with special emphasis on empirical applications, both of the cooperative and of the noncooperative theories.
Tamar Keasar, A. S., & Shur, Y. . (1996).
Overnight Memory Retention of Foraging Skills by Bumblebees Is Imperfect.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 11, Animal Behaviour 52 (1996), 95-104. Retrieved from
/files/dp122.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractNewly emerged bees learn to forage more efficiently as they gain experience. We hypothesized that foraging efficiency would increase as bees gain experience during the day, but would decrease overnight, due to loss of memory. To test this hypothesis, we allowed naive bombus terretris bumblebees to forage on two clusters of artificial flowers of unequal profitabilities during three consecutive days. Nectar intake rate, percentage visitation to the more profitable cluster, probing time and time intervals between visits were computed as measures of the bees' foraging efficiency. Nectar intake rates increased significantly during the day, and decreased partially but significantly after a night. There was much variation between individual bees in nectar intake rates. The bees did not show a preference for one of the clusters at the onset of the experiment, and no consistent increase in visitation to the more profitable cluster was found during single observation days for all bees. Most individuals did not visit the higher-reward cluster exclusively by the end of the third day. However, visitation to the higher-reward cluster did increase significantly when the first day of observation was compared to the third day. Preference for the higher-reward cluster increased over the first night but decreased significantly over the second night. Probing time and inter-visit intervals decreased significantly during observation days, and increased significantly after a night. The results indicate that bees learn to approach and probe flowers faster, as they gain experience, during a foraging day, but that these skills are partially forgotten overnight. Patch preference is formed more slowly. Once formed, it is also weakened overnight. Such partial forgetting may aid the bee in reacting quickly to overnight changes in resource profitability by modifying flower choices and handling techniques.
Okada, A. N., & Daijiro, . (1996).
Repeated Games with Bounded Entropy.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 9, Games and Economic Behavior 30 (2000), 228-247. Retrieved from
/files/dp114.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractWe study the repeated games with a bound on strategic entropy (Neyman and Okada (1996)) of player 1's strategy while player 2's strategy is unrestricted. The strategic entropy bound will be a function (N) of the number of repetitions N, and hence, so is the maximin value of N((N)) of the repeated game with such bound. Our interest is in the asymptotic behavior of N((N)) (as N ) under the condition the per stage entropy bound, (N)/N where 0. We characterize the asymptotics of N((N)) by a continuous function of . Specifically, it is shown that this function is the concavification of the maximin value of the stage game in which player 1's action is restricted to those with entropy at most . We also show that, for infinitely repeated games, if player 1's strategies are restricted to those with strategic entropy rate at most , then the maximin value () exists and it, too, equals the concavified function mentioned above evaluated at .
Amitai, M. . (1996).
Repeated Games with Incomplete Information on Both Sides.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 6. Retrieved from
/files/dp105.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractWe analyze the set of equilibria of two-person repeated games with incomplete information on both sides. We show that each equilibrium generates a martingale with certain properties. Moreover, for games, satisfying a certain condition that we call "tightness", it is shown that the converse also holds: each such martingale generates an equilibrium.
Gershon Ben-Shakhar, 5a Bar-Hillel, Y. B. G. S. . (1996).
Seek and Ye Shall Find: Test Results Are What You Hypothesize They Are.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 11, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 11 (1998), 235-249. Retrieved from
/files/dp123.pdf Publisher's VersionAbstractExpert clinicians were given batteries of psychodiagnostic test results (Rorshach, TAT, Drow-A-Person, Bender-Gestalt, Wechsler) to analyze. For half, a battery came along with a suggestion that the person suffers from Borderline Personality disorder, and for half - that battery was accompanied by a suggestion that he suffers from Paranoid Personality disorder. In study 1, the suggestion was made indirectly, through a background story that preceded the test results. In study 2, the suggestion was made directly, by the instructions given. The experts saw in the tests what they hypothesized to be there. In particular, the target diagnoses were rated higher when they were hypothesized than when they were not.
Weiss, S. H., & Benjamin, Nathans, . (1996).
Significance Levels for Multiple Tests.
Discussion Papers. presented at the 3, Statistics and Probability Letters 35 (1997), 43-48. Retrieved from
/files/ probs.html Publisher's VersionAbstractLet X1, ... , Xn be n random variables, with cumulative distribution functions F1, ... , Fn. define %i := fi(XI) for all i, and let %(1) % ... % %(n) be the order statistics of the (%i)i. Let %1 % ... % %n be n numbers in the interval [0,1]. We show that the probability of the event R := %%(i) % %i for all 1 % i % n %) is at most mini %n%i/i%. Moreover, this bound is exact: for any given n marginal distributions (Fi)i, there exists a joint distribution with these marginals such that the probability of R is exactly mini %n%i/i%. This result is used in analyzing the significance level of multiple hypotheses testing. In particular, it implies that the R?ger tests dominate all tests with rejection regions of type R as above.